The idea of a "public utility" is firmly
entrenched in the minds of most people who live in industrialized countries
today. Things like the water
supply, electric power, and more recent developments such as Internet service
are all considered well-nigh essential to modern life. Most people would probably agree that
because of this, governments have the right to regulate public utilities in a
way that would be regarded as heavy-handed or illegal if the firm involved was
making dental floss, for example, instead of providing a necessity like clean
water or electric power. But I,
for one, never stopped to wonder where the phrase came from until I read a
historical article by Adam Plaiss called "From Natural Monopoly to Public
Utility."
Plaiss traces the origin of the phrase all the way back
to philosopher John Stuart Mill, who used it in a different sense, as a
modifier rather than a noun. Mill
referred to canals and bazaars as works useful to the general public—that is,
works of "public utility."
But the concept that a system of waterworks or communications could be
called a public utility dates back only to the late 1800s, when the related
concept of a natural monopoly began to influence thinkers during what came to
be called the Progressive Era.
Progressives enthused about applying relatively new
social sciences such as economics to pressing public problems such as the
exploitation of the working classes by private monopolistic companies. One of the first professionally-trained
economists in the U. S. was Richard T. Ely, who obtained his doctorate from
Germany and came back to join the effort to apply scientific approaches to
economics as a way of "bring[ing] about a better world." And during a period in the U. S. when
utility companies selling gas, water, electricity, and telephone service were rapidly
expanding, Ely examined the question of a natural monopoly. Was there such a thing, and if so, what
were its characteristics?
Around 1888, Ely came up with a set of criteria that
made an entity a natural monopoly.
The thing it supplied had to be a necessity, like water. The area it served had to be
geographically distinct. And there
could be no wasteful duplication of service within the area. A classic example of what Ely called a
natural monopoly was a water-supply company. The heavy expense of laying pipes and distribution networks
made it virtually impossible for there to be meaningful competition between two
rival water-supply companies for the same customers. So if a service met Ely's criteria for being a natural
monopoly, Ely believed it was the public's right to regulate that service
closely.
Perceptive and thoughtful as Ely was, Plaiss points out
that he had a blind spot when it came to the root cause of a natural
monopoly. Ely attributed the cause
to the nature of the hardware infrastructure itself. But the idea that only private capital could afford to build
utility services was so universally accepted at the time, that Ely failed to
see the contribution of the economic background, so to speak, of late 1800s
America, to the existence of natural monopolies. It is only a slight exaggeration to say that Ely believed
technology caused natural monopolies, not people.
And because Ely saw the creation of natural monopolies
as "technologically determined," as historians put it, he felt it was
necessary for all owners of such monopolies to be subject to government regulation. Otherwise, horrors such as Plaiss cites
in his paper might come about, and did in fact happen in the 1880s and
1890s. For example,
privately-owned water companies in cities such as Houston and Seattle refused
to extend their networks to newer parts of the cities, hampering fire
departments which had no water hydrants to connect to in case of fire. And a typhoid-fever outbreak in
Superior, Wisconsin was caused by impure water provided by a private water
company. Thus, Ely believed that
effective governmental control, if not outright ownership, of natural
monopolies was necessary to prevent the exploitation of the masses that would
result from unregulated private ownership.
After Ely published his thoughts along these lines, a
Progressive journalist named Henry Call first used the phrase "public
utility" as a noun in 1895, meaning by it any organization that enjoys
what Ely would call a natural monopoly in the delivering of what was considered
a modern necessity. Call widened
this category to include "banks, railroads, telegraphs," and
municipal services such as water and gas.
In the coming years, as cities and states established regulatory
commissions and agencies for such utilities, the public got used to the idea
that certain types of business could be categorized as a public utility, and
therefore subjected to regulation.
Many states passed regulatory laws for public utilities in the twenty
years or so after 1900, which saw the height of the Progressive Era. And although the free-market trends of
the 1920s put a damper on further attempts at regulation, the distress of the
Great Depression renewed public enthusiasm for government controls on all sorts
of businesses that looked like public utilities. The establishment of the Federal Communications Commission
in 1933 was square in the tradition of regulating public utilities such as the
air waves, for example.
Since the Progressive Era, the scales of regulation have
swung back and forth. As late as
the 1970s, airlines, the telephone system, and electric utilities in the U. S.
were all closely-regulated and rather dull businesses, guaranteed an annual
profit by their regulatory agencies, but not encouraged to do anything rash or
speculative. By and large, this situation
produced stability and profitability, but discouraged technological
innovation. The spate of
deregulation that began in the 1980s and continues largely to this day
contributed to an explosion of new communications technologies—cable TV, mobile
phones, and the Internet, to mention only a few—but has arguably had its
downsides, as many smaller cities lost air service altogether and the
deregulated electric-power market was gamed by near-criminal enterprises such
as Enron.
With at least the hope of some fresh winds blowing
through Washington these days, we may see a swing of the regulatory pendulum
back toward tighter controls in some services, or looser ones, depending on
whether the interests of the supposedly downtrodden public or of the wealthy
owners of public utilities win out.
But whatever happens, we will do well to remember that
the idea of a public utility is only about 130 years old, and its definition
has twisted and turned with the political winds of the times in which it was
used.
Sources:
"From natural monopoly to public utility: technological determinism and
the political economy of infrastructure in progressive-era America," by
Adam Plaiss, appeared in the Society for the History of Technology journal Technology and Culture (Oct. 2016, vol.
57, no. 4, pp. 806-830).
No comments:
Post a Comment