My personal dealings with the Federal Communications
Commission have been limited to holding a commercial “radio operator” license
that qualified me to be the night watchman at a small AM station for two weeks
in high school, and holding an amateur radio license, which I put in jeopardy
once by building a ham transmitter that splattered signals all over the
40-meter band and got me a “no-no” notice from an FCC monitoring station. Although I am no longer an active ham,
I still have the license, and so I was interested to see a proposal recently
that seemed to threaten not only my license, but those of all ham radio
operators in the U. S.
The proposal is for moving from the present FCC-mandated
allocations of the radio spectrum to something called “open spectrum.” Before I explain what open spectrum
means, I should mention some basics about the radio spectrum and how it is
allocated today.
Radio waves are characterized by their frequency. For example, WRR in Dallas, Texas (one
of the oldest stations west of the Mississippi) operates on a frequency of
101.1 MHz. All the frequencies
from less than 100 kHz (one hundred thousand) up to many GHz (billions) are
usable for communications under some conditions, but you can’t just keep piling
more and more signals onto the same frequencies. Eventually, interference between signals gets so bad that
the whole thing becomes unusable.
A problem like this arose in the 1920s when AM radio broadcasting got
off the ground, and led eventually to the formation of the FCC, along with
international organizations with similar purposes: to regulate how each frequency was used.
Currently, the FCC mandates in most cases exactly who can
use what frequencies and how, and issues licenses to the authorized users,
whether they be hams, radio stations, or wireless hubs that link computers and
cellphones. I said “in most
cases”: there are a few spectrum segments
that are “license-free” and anyone can use these for anything as long as they
follow a few general rules. The
FCC in recent years has also held a limited number of auctions, which is a baby
step toward one form of open-spectrum idea.
You can think of the various open-spectrum proposals as
themselves spread out along a spectrum.
At one end is the old-fashioned central-control approach that the FCC
used prior to about 1985: nobody
does anything without being told exactly where and how to do it by the
FCC. At the other end is the
(impractical) libertarian extreme of no regulations by anyone anywhere, and
everybody just does the best they can.
No one seriously advocates that extreme either, because it would
threaten with disabling interference the investments of many billions of dollars by
operators of cellphone systems, wireless and broadcast networks, and so
on.
The most viable-looking forms of open-spectrum plans
propose something like the following, which was broached in a recent issue of National Review by Christopher
DeMuth. One day the FCC gets up in
the morning and declares that everyone who currently holds a license
henceforward owns property rights in that portion of the spectrum licensed to
them. The licensees can freely buy
and sell their spectrum chunks and use them for anything they like, and the
only role the FCC will play is like the land-records office of a county: just keeping track of who owns
what. DeMuth says that this would
free up a lot of spectrum that is currently misallocated under the old rules,
such as the underutilized spectrum in the UHF TV bands. These vast regions of largely empty MHz
were originally allocated in the 1950s to make up for defects in the crude TV
tuners of the day. But today’s
spread-spectrum and software-radio approaches could exploit these regions much
more effectively, if there were only a way to get at them. DeMuth claims that the form of
open-spectrum policy he advocates would do this and more.
The ethical aspects of open-spectrum notions comes into
play when you consider the radio spectrum as a limited public resource, similar
to a national forest. There is
only so much of it available in a given geographic area, and if you trash it,
you’ll have a lot of problems and it will affect everybody one way or another,
including those who will not be able to afford their present spectrum
allocations under the privatizing style of open-spectrum proposal. The parties who I am concerned about in
the free-market open-spectrum approach are non-profit individuals and
organizations such as radio amateurs (whose licenses explicitly forbid them to
do anything with their hobby for pay), scientists such as radio astronomers,
non-profit agencies of various kinds, and other special cases such as emergency
communications entities with limited budgets.
A different open-spectrum proposal by Professor Eli Noam
at Columbia University would take a less radical approach. Instead of buying and selling, spectrum
users would pay rent based on demand, and the rental fees would go to the
government. Under this proposal,
the non-profit entities could receive protection from the vicissitudes of the
market by having their licenses for free, courtesy of the FCC, much as the
situation is now. But most of the
spectrum would be turned over to a market-based approach where the more
valuable segments would be more costly to use. This idea does most of what the private-ownership concept
does, but leaves a slightly larger role for the government to do what I think
is an appropriate thing: to guard
the rights of those who cannot defend themselves on an economic basis, but who
nevertheless perform useful functions in society.
At the risk of getting more complaints about mentioning
politics, I will say that neither of these open-spectrum proposals seems to
stand much of a chance of getting adopted under an administration which
generally favors top-down approaches to regulation. But I could be wrong, and if enough people of different
political stripes get behind the open-spectrum concept, it could actually
happen. But I hope a form is
adopted which would protect the rights and privileges of those who would no
longer be able to afford to use the spectrum under the totally free-market
approach.
No comments:
Post a Comment